How to Make Trees Worth More Standing Than Cut Down

The Katoomba Group is celebrating 25 years of pioneering new approaches to realizing value in nature. Here’s what we’ve learned. 

West of Sydney, Australia, lies the Blue Mountains, a range of plateaus and panoramic canyons forested with eucalyptus trees. Oil in the leaves produces a bluish haze, hence the name of the area. Twenty-five years ago, in 1999, a new NGO called Forest Trends brought together a small international group to the town of Katoomba to brainstorm over increasing capital flows to protect nature, how to “make trees worth more standing than cut down.” The gathering came to be known as the Katoomba Group and continued hosting gatherings around the world, with core and new participants every year. This loose network played a key role in stimulating payment for ecosystem services (PES) programs at both local and national levels, from Peru and Brazil to Switzerland, Japan and many more. Last week, the group returned to Katoomba to celebrate its 25th anniversary and reflect on the past, present, and future of realizing value in nature.   

I became actively involved at the second Katoomba Group event in Tokyo in 2002 and have worked with the legal and institutional aspects of PES ever since. In a series of blog posts, I will be sharing a few particularly interesting insights from the meeting’s three days of discussion. 

As quick background, the basic driver for a PES approach is that we need much more funding to conserve natural capital than philanthropy and governments can provide. We all depend on natural capital for our well-being. The need could not be more critical.  The last few days have featured headlines of a 73% decline in wildlife over the last 50 years. If you doubt the importance of carbon sequestration, for example, just look at the recent tragedies from storms coming off the Gulf – the 1 in 1,000 year events that climate models predict we should see more and more frequently. 

Today’s blog post will focus on nature-based carbon credits. 

From the earliest days of climate negotiations, there has been intense interest from the environmental community in the possibility of increased funding for forest protection. In principle, it seems a no-brainer. Forests are important carbon sinks and are being cleared at alarming rates in many areas around the globe. The three great forest basins – the Amazon, the Congo, and Southeast Asia – hold 80% of the world’s tropical forests and 66% of terrestrial biodiversity. Only the Congo, however, is still a net carbon sink. If trading mechanisms allow carbon emissions from one area to be offset by afforestation or reduced rates of deforestation, the climate is better off. 

Easy to say. Not so easy to do.  

As many readers will know, there have been legitimate concerns over leakage, permanence, and additionality of nature-based carbon credits. Not to mention outright fraud. When John Oliver does an 18-minute take down of offsets on his HBO show, you know there are problems. Nor does it help when Delta Airlines is sued for fraud for its $1 billion commitment to purchase carbon credits so it can achieve carbon neutrality. There was a great deal of discussion at the Katoomba Group meetings about loss of trust.  

Does this mean that nature-based carbon credits are fundamentally flawed and should just be rejected? Some respected scholars and environmentalists are of this view. The view of most Katoomba participants, however, was that this would be a mistake. Here are some reasons why. 

We are still in the early days of a market.   

Any time a new market emerges, there is a good deal of snake oil for sale. When there is an easy way to make a buck, there will be fraud. Over time, however, mechanisms emerge to identify the high-value products and remove the junk. This can happen through stringent government regulation, reputation, private certification, or some combination of these. The LEAF Coalition, for example, is a coalition of over 25 major companies focused on purchasing high-quality forest carbon credits. Control over the entire selection and verification process provides a much greater assurance of quality than relying on third parties.  Put simply, we should expect many of the quality problems that have emerged with credits, but these should diminish over time as quality assurance mechanisms develop. 

Recognize the Additionality Double Standard.

Most of the criticisms of credits focus on additionality – are we getting value for the money or would the action have happened, anyway? If a company gets credits by paying to conserve a forest on a plot of land, proving additionality requires showing that the forest would likely have been logged absent the payment. If the forest was unlikely to be cut down, this is a waste of money and bogus credits. A well-publicized early carbon credit project, for example, turned out to be for protecting a bird refuge, the last place you’d expect to be logged.  

Don’t get me wrong – additionality is genuine concern. But I would argue (and have argued) that we are using a double standard. The fact is that additionality risks arise in many policies throughout government with far more money at stake than with offsets, from Medicare and Low-income Housing Tax Credits to the recently passed Inflation Reduction Act (IRA). The IRA provides a subsidy for purchases of electric vehicles for people making less than $300,000 per year. Would many of these people have bought EV’s, anyway? Probably so, but we don’t denounce the IRA as fatally flawed because of its additionality problems. The key question is how much lack of additionality is acceptable, not whether none exists at all. As above, we should expect less of this problem as the market matures. 

Keep your eyes on the prize.

The bottom line is that roughly 99% of carbon emissions are unregulated or not offset at all. And even among those companies that do practice offsetting, total credit purchases make up an average of less than 3% of their overall carbon footprint. The other 97% they’re addressing directly in their operations/value chain. Credits are a tiny part of the picture. Meanwhile, deforestation continues apace and greenhouse gas concentrations continue to rise toward irreversible tipping points. Simply calling for more effective regulation has not been adequate to halt this trend. I see no reason why that will change any time soon. This is a situation of “yes, and…” Regulations matter, but we also need to change the incentives of landowners on the ground.  

Credits provide an important mechanism to do so. If the offsets are bogus or not additional, they should not be sold. If they harm local communities, they should not be sold. But I think it’s a mistake to reject categorically a major source of potential funds that can help make trees worth more standing than cut down. We don’t have the luxury of throwing away solutions if they can be improved. 

Thus the key question is whether the nature-based credit market can develop over time to minimize these problems so that they become as acceptable as in every other government policy, warts and all. I’m optimistic this can be done, as were most of the Katoomba participants. Trust is hard to build, and easily lost. People are right to be suspicious of offset credits. Suing Delta for fraud, though, strikes me as counterproductive. What signal does that send to other companies trying to take carbon neutrality seriously? I get that this makes sense if you think offset credits are fundamentally flawed. My view is that they can be made genuinely credible, just as we have seen in other emerging markets.  

The next blog will focus on corporate disclosure of carbon and natural capital risks. 

, , , , , ,

Reader Comments

6 Replies to “How to Make Trees Worth More Standing Than Cut Down”

  1. Thanks for the interesting post, Jim. My wife’s mother lives in Black Heath in the Blue Mountains, and we’ve spent a lot of time in Katoomba, so cool to find out about this work.

    One quibble I have with the post: I don’t think that the question of additionality in the context of programs like the IRA and EVs is nearly as salient as in the context of carbon crediting. In the former case, yes, there may be some wasting of government funds, and perhaps one could argue that it could be invested better in other climate solutions, but this is pretty speculative. By contrast, when one grants an emitters a dodgy offset, either in the compliance or voluntary markets, you’re clearly permitting them to emit more carbon in the atmosphere, which has a pretty direct impact on the climate. As a consequence, I don’t think it’s really a “double standard” to be very focused on offset integrity.

  2. Hi Wil, This is a point David Weisbach and I heard a lot with our original Harvard Environmental Law Review article — who cares if we are just spending some extra money? That’s different than emissions and offsets. Here is our response in the article:

    Itt appears that lack of additionality for most subsidies means
    merely that a policy goal is not met efficiently. Paying for medical care for individuals who would otherwise have purchased it, as in the case of Medicare, may
    waste money but it is not viewed as undermining the integrity of the program,
    harming people, or letting bad actors continue their bad behavior. Low-income
    housing tax credits reduce the cost of housing, even if they do so inefficiently
    by not ensuring all credits generate new housing. Developers who build nonadditional units are not necessarily bad actors harming the world. These and
    other programs suffer from lack of additionality, but unlike with polluters using
    carbon offsets, there is not an obviously bad actor. We can always just spend
    more on health care, housing, food, or other policies to meet our goals. Put
    another way, non-additionality in carbon offsets creates moral culpability that is
    not present when talking about subsidies more generally.
    This argument, however, while attractive at first glance, does not meaningfully distinguish most subsidy programs from carbon offsets. To start, while
    there surely are bad actors, it is not obvious that all 5,200 companies and the
    33 nations making net zero promises are morally culpable. Moreover, there are
    likely bad actors in many subsidy programs. To illustrate, while the morality of
    gentrification is complex and we take no position on it here, many view developers gentrifying poor neighborhoods as bad actors.If they build non-additional
    low-income housing, subsidized by the LIHTC, they may claim that they have
    “offset” the gentrification because they have not reduced the number of low income units on the market. If the units are non-additional, however, they have
    done no such thing. The problem is precisely the same as the bad carbon polluter
    who buys carbon offsets. Many subsidy programs can present similar problems
    with moral dimensions.
    More importantly, the central goal for climate policy is reducing emissions. Most subsidy programs have similar types of goals, such as providing
    healthcare, housing, or nutrition for people who cannot otherwise afford these
    items. In all these cases, climate change and other policy areas, the goal is to get
    more of a good or less of a bad. We want fewer emissions of greenhouse gases,
    but also fewer food-insecure people, fewer people without access to housing or
    health care. Money “wasted” on actions or services that would have occurred
    anyway could have gone much farther to prevent harm to society if the funds had been better directed to ensure additional good services and actions. For
    example, if school lunches are non-additional, the reduction in childhood food
    insecurity is not as large as we might have hoped in the same way that if offsets
    are non-additional, emissions of carbon dioxide do not go down by the amount
    promised.

  3. All the carbon credits in the world combined have not resulted in any reduction in global atmospheric temperature whatsoever.

    Regulating CO2 emissions has no proven effect on climate. The actual level of CO2 in the atmosphere continues to increase. 98% of CO2 emissions are natural and cannot be controlled.

    Global climate cannot be controlled, reduced, modulated, or mitigated by human efforts, all attempts to do so have consistently failed. Therein lies the fraud (additionality is irrelevant).

    The authors, lawyers, journalists, and contributors to Legal Planet have never provided even one credible example, project or experiment whereby global climate was actually reduced, even a little bit, by regulating CO2 emissions.

    Worthless climate mitigation will eventually be abandoned altogether. Instead we should focus on adaptation which is relatively easy and inexpensive. Have a good day and don’t worry about the weather.

    1. See Evan’s example below and David’s after that pointing out why mitigation matters. For what it’s worth, I view the mitigation-adaptation issue not as an “either, or” but as a “yes, and”.

  4. California’s emissions of carbon dioxide shrank by about 9.3 million metric tons in 2022 compared to 2021, which others have noted is the equivalent of removing 2.2 million gasoline-powered vehicles from the road for a year. Much of those reductions came from transportation as Californians bought more EVs and less gas, cargo trucks that ferry goods from ports and rail yards are more reliant on crop-based biofuels instead of conventional diesel fuel.

    https://ww2.arb.ca.gov/sites/default/files/2024-09/nc-2000_2022_ghg_inventory_trends.pdf

  5. I have a brother who lives in what is left of Chimney Rock, NC. He definitely worries about the weather and so should we all for obvious reasons. Increased CO2 is increasing the atmospheric temperature in accordance with the Clausius-Clapeyron relation, which means that for every degree Celsius increase the atmosphere holds 7% more water vapor. This in turn amplifies the warming effect of other greenhouse gases in a positive feedback loop.

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *

About Jim

James Salzman is the Donald Bren Distinguished Professor of Environmental Law with joint appointments at the UCLA School of Law and at the Bren School of the Environment …

READ more

About Jim

James Salzman is the Donald Bren Distinguished Professor of Environmental Law with joint appointments at the UCLA School of Law and at the Bren School of the Environment …

READ more

POSTS BY Jim